Within hours of his inauguration, President Biden had rolled back various immigration restrictions put in place across the last 4 years. Not only is this morally commendable, it represents an economic free lunch for the US!
The economics 101 of migration
Before diving into the literature, let’s start with four first-pass ways to tackle the question of whether immigration is good for the receiving country!
Supply and demand. An influx of immigrants increases the supply of labour, while them spending increases the demand for labour. At first blush, that means the effect on the price of labour i.e. wages, is ambiguous.
Neoclassical growth model. An influx of immigrants raises the marginal product of capital, since capital and labour are complementary inputs in production. This incentivises people to invest in capital accumulation until the capital-labour ratio reaches its original level again. There is a short-run fall in GDP per capita while capital is still accumulating, but in the long run, the effects are entirely neutral.
Endogenous growth model. An influx of immigrants raises the total number of people who are working on research and development. Since new ideas and innovations are non-rivalrous, there is a positive effect on growth in the long run.
Immigration as natalism. An influx of immigrations has the same effect on population size as if people chose to have more babies, and yet no one worries about whether every generation being larger will push down wages or employment.
To be clear, none of these are close to perfect models of the world. Importantly, they all ignore heterogeneity within labour markets. The demographic composition and characteristics of immigrations are not identical to the native workforce, so to delve deeper than these aggregate heuristics, let’s take a look at the empirical literature!
The empirical literature
Firstly, we can try to resolve the ambiguity mentioned previously - between 1980 and 2000, the increased demand caused by immigrants meant that each immigrant created 1.2 native jobs in the US i.e. the effect of greater demand dominated1. Secondly, even the increased labour supply can be helpful - because immigrants accept lower wages, this decreases the average labour cost and means that more jobs for natives are created. Consequently, the legalisation of more immigration can raise income for native workers, based on a model calibrated to the economies of the US and Mexico from 2000 to 2010.
Notice these benefits occur even when the immigrants are low-skilled. This is because of a third mechanism, where low-skilled immigrants caused low-skilled native workers in the US to pursue careers in which they have the comparative advantage, such as those which are less manual-intensive and involve more communications. Notice that this results from the fact that even within the category of low-skilled workers, immigrants are imperfect substitutes for natives - a good example would be in California, where immigration stimulated the demand and wages of native workers between 1960 and 2004. Similarly, the wages, employment and occupational mobility of unskilled native workers in Denmark actually saw an increase as a result of low-skilled immigrants. Crucially, this effect is seen further downstream, with the net effect of a 1 percentage point increase in the share of the population from ages 11 to 64 increasing the probability of natives aged 11 to 17 completing 12 years of schooling by 0.3 percentage points. In doing so, it enhances the earning possibilities of natives.
Furthermore, even in the cases where immigrants are substitutes and cause wages to fall in the short run, these seem to be very minimal due to the ability for firms to adjust their production technologies, as seen in the US in the early 1900s as well as in the 1980s and 1990s. This has been corroborated by the 1964 bracero exclusion in the US, which had no effect on domestic workers despite increasing immigration barriers and reducing the labour supply.
High-skilled innovation
These are buttressed by a second sort of benefits, relating to high-skilled immigrants in particular. In the US, immigrants are twice as likely to be granted patents and to start new businesses. In fact, a 1 percentage point increase in the share of college-graduated immigrants boosts patents per capita by up to 18%. This effect was seen in citations too, with areas having more prevalent immigrant inventors between 1880 and 1940 seeing more citations from 1940 to 2000.
In part, this is a function of self-selection - for example, Mexican immigrants to the US are disproportionately educated compared to Mexico’s average. Consequently, STEM immigrants have had a significant direct effect on increasing TFP growth in the US between 1990 and 2010, in addition to raising wages for both college-educated and non-college-educated native workers. This is augmented by the fact that cultural diversity itself also accrues benefits to productivity.
The result of all of this is that more relaxed immigration restrictions were associated with innovation and within a state, an increase of employment by 1% due to immigrants led to an increase in income per worker of 0.5%. As seen in Brazil, the influx of these high-skilled immigrants has long run benefits with respect to income per capita and the level of education.
Net effects of immigration
The consequence of all of this is that across 22 OECD countries between 1986 and 2006, the overall impact of immigration on per capita GDP is positive, even where immigration policies are non-selective. To the extent to which there are mixed or negative effects, these are very small and very much limited to previous waves of immigrants or natives without a high school diploma. And because of the composition of immigrants in the US, coupled with the pace of production technology adjustment, the negative effects on the absolute or relative wages of even those groups have been very limited.
Identification and the Mariel boatlift
All of the studies above involve very careful identification strategies, because as we all know, correlation does not imply causation. Immigrants may well be drawn to economically booming areas and leave economically weaker areas - as such, it is very useful if there is a natural experiment, where an exogenous shock causes immigration for non-economic reasons. The most prominent case of this is the Mariel Boatlift.
After 20 years of no immigration between Cuba and Miami, Fidel Castro lifted the ban on Cubans to emigrate in 1980. In the span of half a year, around 125,000 Cubans immigrated to Miami from the Mariel harbour in Cuba. This resulted in the Miami workforce rising by 7% that year, compared to the national average of 0.3% per annum. If there was going to be an effect on wages and employment from immigration, it would happen here. This would be especially pronounced for low-skilled workers, since most of the immigrants were low-skilled. And yet, Professor David Card found in his seminal study that there was basically no effect on low-skilled workers, even including those who had immigrated earlier.
Importantly, this was not because the workers who faced a wage drop moved away. Rather, it involved an increased labour demand and the adoption of production technology which use more low-skilled labour.
Famously, there was a contradictory study by Professor George Borjas, who argued that because 60% of the Marielitos did not have a high school diploma, the relevant comparison was not just those with a high school diploma or less, but only those who had dropped out of high school. By isolating only those individuals, there was a dramatic drop in wages of up to 30%.
Unfortunately, Borjas’s study looks at a very specific sample - it takes everyone with a high school diploma or less and then excludes women, Hispanics, non-prime age workers (between 19-24 and 60-65 years old) and those with a high school diploma. That results in 17 workers every year - that is, 91% of the data points have been stripped away. The problem with such a tiny statistical artifact is that it’s results are not terribly representative and very sensitive to changes in methodology.
As it turns out, the way some of the data was found was changed after the boatlift, with far more black workers being included than before. Due to their lower earnings on average in that specific situation, this exaggerated the wage decline. Unfortunately, it is impossible to exclude black workers from Borjas’s analysis, because that leaves us with 4 observations a year i.e. 98% of the data is gone. If the composition of those interviewed for data collection is instead adjusted for, Borjas’s result is much more fragile. And if we simply took the group of all high school dropouts, the result disappears entirely. So the main takeaway from the Mariel boatlift is that the general premise from before remains true!
Inequality and welfare
Clearly employment and wages matter - but they aren’t the be all and end all. Some have argued that there are less obvious costs of having immigrants, in the form of more inequality and larger welfare costs. By now, it should be clear that it is unlikely inequality will be significantly affected by immigration, insofar as the skill distribution of immigrants in places like the UK are very similar to the native workforce. To the extent to which they increase inequality, they do so because they are concentrated on the high-skilled and low-skilled sections of the workforce, and do not increase inequality for the native workforce. Instead, things like skill-based technology change i.e. automation, housing prices and fiscal policy are much more responsible.
As for public finances and welfare programs, most studies find that immigrants produce a positive net fiscal effect. In part, this is because even illegal immigrants pay taxes. It is also because poor immigrants use welfare less than comparable natives. Indeed, even undocumented immigrants contribute more than they cost the public.
To the extent to which immigrants take more than they put in, this only occurs for first-generation ones, because of the high costs of childrearing, though even this doesn’t occur more so than for native parents. Furthermore, this is paid back by the second generation of immigrants, who are stronger economic contributers than even natives. By considering both the labour market effects and the impacts on government redistribution, a general equilibrium model applied across 20 OECD countries finds that immigration improves wellbeing of both high-skilled and low-skilled natives.
Assimilation, crime and refugees
Another angle of opposition to immigration is about non-pecuniary factors - specifically, their ability to assimilate and not get involved with criminal activities. In general, migrant assimilate culturally - for example, the social values of Muslim immigrants are somewhere between that of their own country and that of their country of destination. Another example would be the fact that immigrants to the US are learning English at a faster rate than ever before. And this is reflected in the fact that second-generation immigrants following the 1965 Immigration Reform Act in the US have on average higher education levels and wages than children of natives, suggesting they’ve caught up and assimilated rather quickly. And while it is true that not every immigrant community has assimilated, a lot of this is down to a bad equilibrium - for example, this is exemplified by how French discrimination against Muslims may lead to a reluctance to assimilate, making their incongruity even more salient and causing even more discrimination.
Certainly however, this does not mean their lack of assimilation causes crimes. A meta-analysis suggests that there is practically zero magnitude association between immigration and crime. In fact, foreign-born immigrants are less likely than the average native to commit crimes, with immigrants to the US being incarcerated at a fifth of the rate of natives. As with the previous areas, being an undocumented immigrant doesn’t change this finding either. Where crime does occur, this is usually for financial motives and related to poor labour market outcomes.
Importantly, the benefits of immigration are robust to those entering the country being refugees, who still contribute positively to the economy. Although it is true that refugees generally start out less successful and being more low-skilled, they surpass within 15 years, earning and improving their human capital more than economic immigrants.
Spatial misallocation
We’ve spent a lot of time discussing the benefits of immigration. But throughout all of this, we haven’t discussed the most important people: the migrants themselves. The reason why making migration easier is useful, above all else, is because borders are arbitrary constraints that cause the spatial misallocation of labour. The biggest cause of cross-country income disparity is TFP differences, caused by gaps in technologies and institutions - by artificially trapping labour in places that are deeply unproductive, we are losing out on a huge amount of potential output.
For example, it is found that the place premium i.e. the disparity in wages between identical workers in different countries, of a medium-skilled worker from a median country moving to the US is on the order of $10,000 per annum. In other words, this is roughly double income per capita in the developing world. Indeed, we can see this by considering the income per capita, organised not by which country one is in but by which country one was born in - when considered thusly, we can see that 40% of living Mexicans escaped poverty by leaving Mexico and that rises to 80% for Haitians.
Certainly, this would be one of the most powerful development policies available, to the order of 40 times more effective than any sort of direct aid interventions. Open borders would yield welfare gains equivalent to a miraculous doubling of income levels in developing countries. In the words of Dr. Michael Clemens, there are “trillion dollar bills [lying] on the sidewalk”. And although it is true that there is a danger of migrants transmitting low productivity, we are nowhere close to that being a problem.
If migration is so helpful for the individuals who leave, doesn’t this leave their countries of origin hung out to dry? As it turns out, it doesn’t. Emigration has a positive net effect even on the sending country. This occurs via various channels: of remittances, of the possibility of emigration encouraging human capital formation, of emigrants building the trust needed to get FDI back to their home country and of encouraging the formation of inclusive institutions via the propagation of cultural ideas.
Migration as a free lunch
It is clear that the fact of a downwards sloping demand curve doesn’t automatically prove that immigration is harmful, especially when it is based on faulty assumptions regarding capital being fixed, the composition of native workers and immigrants being perfect substitutes for native workers.
In reality, a broad survey of the literature paints a much more encouraging picture. This is one of significant benefits to immigrants without noticeable harms on native workers, government services or public finances. Insofar as most problems around labour market outcomes, assimilation and welfare program usage of immigrants are negatively correlated with human capital accumulation, making legal immigration easier solves most of those.
In economics, we often say that there are no free lunches. But reducing migration barriers comes as close to a free lunch as it gets. Given the tiny harms and the ease of solving them, as well as the magnitude of the benefits to the receiving country, individual migrants and even the country of origin, the obvious solution is to make immigration easier and to open up borders.